最受歡迎 30天 | Most Popular 30 days

Saturday, April 16, 2016

SMART來分析一下「無核家園」



不少大公司的管理訓練課,有SMART教程。工作項目無論大小,必須通過SMART檢驗。S:specific具體性,要制定具體可行的工作,否則就淪為空談;M:measurable可檢測性,檢驗工作是否達到預期進度;A:achievable成功性,時時要問,這項工作做得成嗎?R:reliable可靠性,安全可靠,如有危險,應如何防範救援?T:timeline日程表,掌握完成工作的時間進程,避免延誤,造成耗損。
挺有道理也很有趣,拿個例子來做練習。大家所熟知的「反攻大陸」,它符合SMART嗎?早年大家天天唱「反攻反攻大陸去」、作文結尾都用幾句反攻的套話,記得有個登陸東山島戰役,敗下陣來。回溯歷史,其實很少有具體的反攻行動。「反攻大陸」是既定國策,誰敢問它的進度?問東問西是思想有問題,所以它不具有可檢測性。反攻大陸能成功嗎?要待共匪「腐爛年」的即將到來。一說要等到美蘇啟動第三次世界大戰,反攻大陸就可以隨之而上,一舉成功。反攻大陸是個可靠的計畫嗎?軍事專家早有答案,海峽兩岸實力懸殊,怎麼打呀?得靠美國老大哥出動幫忙,可是人家連協防台灣都不肯明白的說出來。反攻大陸完全沒有日程表,曾經有個口號:一年準備、二年反攻、三年掃蕩、五年成功;轉眼好幾個五年過去,還在繼續準備。
「反攻大陸」通過不了SMART的檢測,做不成的,大家跟著喊口號罷了。老講這個老掉牙的事,年輕人聽不下去,不如找件當下的事務來說說。
「無核家園、電價不漲」是人人都關心、也都贊成的大事,沒有人願意見到台灣發生核災難。就以SMART來分析一下:
要達成「無核家園」的具體工作是什麼?封存建成的第四核電廠,其他三座核電廠按照既定日程退役。還該做什麼?目前核能電廠供應百分之十八的全台用電量,全面廢棄核電廠後,以燃煤、天然氣、綠能源代替核電,具體計畫為何,第一步要做什麼?選舉已經結束,不必爭取選票了,還在順口說說是過不去的。燒煤和天然氣會造成過量的二氧化碳,發展綠色能源的投資大,據說全球還沒有一個國家的綠能發電,能應付百分之十的供電量。
倒是訂出了一個期限:二○二五年台灣全面廢止核能發電。為什麼訂在那一年,是個一廂情願的日期?沒有工作進度日程表,因為做什麼工作都不清楚!如何檢測無核家園的進展;具體工作一律說不出來,又檢驗那項工作進度?
「無核家園」能成功嗎?福島核災三年後,日本政府宣稱:日本要繼續靠部分核能發電來供應全國的用電,日本做不到的事,台灣能做到?很少有人問這個問題,所以也聽不到答案了。
發展綠能需要很長的過程,九年時間能發展出什麼綠色能源來,可靠可用嗎?也不知道。距離那個日子只剩下九年多,光陰似箭,「無核家園、電價不漲」難道又是一句政治口號?
SMART是近代工商管理學發展出來的一套理論和方法,證明有它的功能。盡信書不如無書,也不必將它當成金科玉律。但是事務無法通過SMART檢驗,它就不算SMART了,該叫它什麼呢?(作者為電影導演)

避免下一個浩鼎案

避免下一個浩鼎案

中研院長翁啟惠回台說明似乎無法解疑。回顧整個浩鼎案的發展,浩鼎高層介入操弄個股股價,斧鑿甚深。首先,2月21日的解盲記者會,浩鼎公司利用民眾對解盲相關數據知識不足,刻意將失敗的臨床試驗解盲結果,操弄成「失敗中的成功」,迷惑投資大眾,令浩鼎股價得以繼續維持高檔。
其次,3月31日,浩鼎生技以解盲報告被美國ASCO學會接受並將於今年6月赴美發表為由,向證期會通報發布重大訊息,申請停止交易一日。但浩鼎當天記者會中,卻以ASCO要求相關解盲資訊不得事先透露,拒絕向社會公布。再度凸顯浩鼎利用現行股票監理制度缺失,繼續玩弄社會大眾。
面對浩鼎案,我們應該記取教訓,亡羊補牢。具體建議如下:第一,現行金管會甚至證期局,對於新興產業投入股票市場的相關管理規範以及專業知識明顯不足,以至於業者能遊走法律邊緣、恣意操弄股價。為今之道,唯有延聘更多其他領域的專家學者,方能解決金管會、證期局只懂金融,不瞭解產業的困境。
新藥的解盲程序是一個單純的科學步驟,但浩鼎將簡單的結果複雜化,宣稱「失敗中的成功」,則證期局必須要求它提供更多的資訊,供國人檢證。
第二,解盲程序以及標準的市場資訊公開規範應即刻建立。生技在我國仍屬新興產業,現行法規對於該產業相關市場資訊公開規範仍顯不足。證期局應訂定解盲會議的標準作業流程(SOP),未來有關解盲說明會,相關研究團隊、專家學者以及政府管理代表都應該列席。凡生技公司做出成功或失敗以外的推論,都應該立即接受提問與釋疑,否則即有操弄市場嫌疑,應予以重罰。
第三,生技產業聲請暫停交易事由應更明確。股票市場中的暫停交易機制原為保障投資人因資訊不對稱而造成個股交易異常之現象。此次浩鼎公司竟以解盲論文被ASCO接受為由聲請暫停交易,實屬制度之特例。美國大藥廠每年動輒30、40餘篇論文被ASCO接受,亦未見其聲請停止交易。再者,浩鼎解盲論文被ASCO接受與新藥許可上市,兩者之間未必有任何關係。貿然停止交易恐造成股票交易市場與國際脫軌。
今浩鼎案傷害既已造成,除斲損相關生技人才聲譽外,亦暴露金管單位面對新興產業無法與時俱進的現況。未來應即刻制訂生技產業解盲程序以及標準的市場資訊公開規範,避免公司高層利用資訊不對稱等類似方式,坑殺一般投資大眾。   (作者為立法委員)

大陸網友的順口溜:

大陸網友的順口溜:

 十個台胞九個騙,還有一個當教練;
 十萬台胞九萬騙,還有一萬在訓練;
藍綠名嘴當教練,總部設在立法院;
 肯亞印尼菲律賓,處處都有連鎖店;  
 狂發簡訊打電話,誓把大陸搜刮遍;
 核心技術不外流,台灣騙術有夠賤;
 如果被抓不要怕,遣回台灣繼續騙;
 法官輕放滅天理,下流無恥不要臉;
 立委瞎挺還敢辯,法務部長照樣電;
 大家跟我一起唸,只要不怕討人厭;
 坑爹騙娘無上限,保你發財賽火箭;
 歡迎加入詐騙鍊,得手有錢氣勢燄;
 禮義廉恥全不見,啊,台灣經驗真驚艷。

輸了面子,也輸了裡子,輸到脫褲子。只能多買些褲子了。

輸了面子,也輸了裡子,輸到脫褲子。只能多買些褲子了。

台灣輸到脫褲襤;

台灣海外電信詐騙案,肯亞案,馬來西亞案緊連著端上桌。
 北京一抓一放,似乎標準不一,其實很有節奏,台灣政治人物也非常配合北京節拍起舞。
 北京算計極深,台灣卻毫無章法,台灣將輸到脫褲襤。

 肯亞案,罪嫌全部抓到北京調查。
 台灣政治人物馬上叫,堅持國家主權,台灣人應帶回台灣自己管,北京傷害台灣人的感情。

北京豈會沒預料到這些人會怎麼反應?
 馬英九蔡英文會怎麼說,很難預想嗎?
 段宜康,顧立雄,黃國昌,管碧玲等立委會怎麼叫?不必太強的智庫都料得著。
 台灣的思考已極制式,極其單一,極好預料。

台灣叫完了,好了,馬來西亞案,就全照你們要求的,都交給你台灣,看你怎麼辦?

台灣能怎麼辦?無罪推定原則,海外犯罪,罪嫌不足,還不是依菲律賓案模式,馬上把20人都放了?黃國昌真是搶救有功啊!

肯亞案,北京把人抓回一天,就已調查出眉目了,新華社馬上報導。痕跡多顯著?就是要展現他們辦案十分積極。
 除了速查外,接下來還會速審速結速刑。

等北京都把這干詐騙犯判刑服監了,馬來西亞案的罪嫌呢?
 極大可能還到處趴趴走,甚至再度前往第三國,重操舊業。

兩案幾乎同時上桌,或許也是北京刻意安排,才有個對比。
 兩案對比,彼岸嚴厲打擊犯罪,我岸卻是罪犯樂土。
 不僅大陸人氣不過,台灣人也會一肚子悶氣:我們真的是詐騙犯的天堂嗎?

未來,尤其五二0後,可能還有更多案,台灣怎麼辦?
 要不要再大聲叫,接這些詐騙嫌犯回台?
 以前叫那麼大聲,台灣主權人民感情調子唱得那麼高,也不能不繼續叫。
 但叫有用嗎?北京是不會再讓台灣接的了。

到時總統蔡英文,外交部長李大維,陸委會主委張小月,你們怎麼辦?
立委們,你們要怎麼說?
法務部長邱太三如管碧玲建議,開個國際記者會譴責北京?
陸委會依陳其邁主張,限制台灣人去大陸,來制裁大陸嗎?
或許只能依陳歐珀說法,這些是"善良無罪"的台灣人。台灣當然沒有關善良無罪的道理。

大聲叫,要求把台灣人送回來
 人家只要問:肯亞案罪犯,在大陸這邊已在服刑了;幾乎同時間的馬來西亞案,台灣,你們呢?案情如何?罪嫌人在哪裡?

台灣輸了面子,也輸了裡子,輸到脫褲子。

對台灣政客來說,馬來西亞案最有利的結局是,在北京堅持下,繼續押到大陸。
政客可以繼續罵北京鴨霸,民眾情緒可以繼續沸騰,政客收利最大。

但北京更會打算盤,竟然不堅持,就讓你台灣帶回去吧,你辦得了嗎?你關得了嗎?
 被這麼一戮,台灣政客將洩了氣,原來的大聲嚷嚷是那麼沒底氣,
 不僅受害的大陸人憤怒,飽經詐騙之苦的台灣人也會一肚子氣。

北京老謀深算,不僅算清了台灣政治人物的反應,也估準了大陸及台灣的民情。
台灣政治人物再不長進,只會反射動作,那台灣一切都將在北京算計當中,台灣只能多買些褲子了。



歡迎訂閱 My Blog

葉金川:如果我沒醒來,不要串通醫師凌遲我!

--------- Forwarded message ----------

Subject: 葉金川:如果我沒醒來,不要串通醫師凌遲我!



葉金川:如果我沒醒來,不要串通醫師凌遲我!
文/葉金川(前衛生署署長)

應該不是「如果」,
而是必然有這麼一天,
我們必須說再見!

「葉家宴」不會一直開,
天下宴席總要散的。

根據生命表,
19 年後,要跟大家說再見,
但,可能是下一刻,
也可以是38 年後;
就怕還沒準備,
匆忙間上路,重要的忘了說,
不如現在說個透澈。

兒子們,記著:
如果我沒醒過來,
不要串通醫師凌遲我!

我想活得精彩、走得帥氣,
不要管子,
有氣切管、尿管、胃管,
怕走得牽絆;
停止維生治療吧!
多拖幾天,
並不會增添生命的色彩。

心臟升壓劑、洗腎、葉克膜,
省省吧!
健保都快倒了…。

能用的,都送人,
心肝應還是好的;
有了我的心,
可以登高看更遠。
有我的肝,
酒量不會退步!

至少眼角膜、骨頭可以用,
腎臟最珍貴,我腎沒有虛。

兒子,
孝順爸媽,趁現在!
我走了以後,
孝順就成了做樣子、給外人看的;
所以--
追思葬禮省了,
墓園、墓碑也不環保,
偶而,
將爸爸放在心裡,
就可以了。

骨灰要火化,
混合飼料,丟七星潭餵魚吧!
留下一小撮,帶到合歡北峰,
灑些許就好;
切記,
別給太魯閣國家公園逮到!

孩子們,請記得:牽著你們媽咪來看我,
平日裡嫌她嘮叨,
沒人唸了,倒是有點不習慣,
有老伴,很幸福的,
感恩啦,老婆。

親朋好友們:
不用來,
沒有追思會,
白包也省了。
如果堅持要付,
現在預付打六折,我可現用。

網路上留有我生前語錄,
還有給大家的真心話,
沒事?
上網看看,也許會有新靈感。

想我的時候,
我們合歡北峰見!
看看高山杜鵑,
帶瓶香檳,
──別忘了高腳杯,
喝酒可是要有規矩的;
這次,
我們一飲而盡吧!

能來,不必挑時辰,任何時候都歡迎;
但,四到六月高山杜鵑遍地招展時最好,那也是清明時節;
我來教你們看星座:
天蠍心宿二、
牛郎織女天津四、
獵戶大犬、
冬季正三角。

不會看?
可別說是我山友,
這樣我多沒面子呀!
可以接受--
不爬山的山友、
不騎車的車友、
不喝酒的酒友、
最不能忍受-
看不懂星座的山友!

我一生清風,
但求身後化為千風,
了無遺憾。

愛你們的
葉金川

摘自`如果有一天,我們說再見`

An informed critique of economics

An informed critique of economics


The Economics of Innocent Fraud
Is Economics 'The Biggest Fraud Ever Perpetrated on the World?
ECONOMICS: THE BIGGEST FRAUD EVER PERPETRATED ON THE WORLD?

An informed critique of economics 
The case against economics:
  • The promise economics offers is seductive: how to allocate scarce resources in society. It's a false promise.[2]
  • Economists write as if the economy=society, and societal problems=economic problems. The conflation is false too.[3]
  • Once there was political economy = economics, ethics, politics. Economists have stripped morality from economics, leaving an arid science.[4]
  • The high points of economic thinking are theories, not data. Reliable experimentally derived data are anathema for most economists.[5]
  • Economists see health as an economic good. It is an opportunity cost, with zero intrinsic value.[6]
  • Rationality, for the economist, means subjecting every thought/decision to a cost-benefit analysis. A wholly narrow view of humanity.[7]
  • The big idea in economics is the market. The assumption is that human beings make cost-benefit decisions based only on self-interest. No.[8]
  • The essence of economics is price. For those in health who argue for access free at point of delivery, we kill the soul of the economist.[9]
  • Economists deny the existence of citizens. They see only consumers.[10]
  • Finally, it's acceptable to worsen the lives of some provided the gains of others compensate. Economists institutionalise inequality.[11]
Apart from a natural inclination to defend our chosen profession, our response to Horton's criticisms tackles what we see as some fundamental misconceptions about economics and economists—among other things, their motivation, view of life, and understanding of others' motivations and behaviours. We believe that economics is a toolkit that enables better understanding of how people live, and how societies work. In doing so, it gathers and analyses data with statistical methods, formulates theories, constructs models of complex systems, and sometimes makes predictions. Economics is not a way of life, nor does it aim to promote one—although many economists do express preferences for societal goals such as low unemployment, reduced inequalities, and improved health, as do many other people. Economics does not exclude, or seek to exclude, other explanations of human behaviour—from the anthropological to the psychological—but adds another dimension to understanding why people do what they do.
What is economics about? “The promise economics offers is seductive: how to allocate scarce resources in society. It's a false promise.”[2] “Economists write as if the economy=society, and societal problems=economic problems. The conflation is false too.”[3] The first two tweets are more an introduction than a cogent set of criticisms. Economics is, apparently, a “fraud”, and offers a “false promise”. There is no evidence given to support these assertions, so we cannot answer the case. The statement that economics concerns the allocation of scarce resources in society is true, but in the tweets that follow, Horton makes false conflations of his own. In a paper first written for a medical audience, Alan Williams [12] distinguishes between economics as a topic and as a discipline: the object of study of economics, and the way in which it is studied. Economists did not invent the economy. It is a social phenomenon that has a history far longer than that of economics. Economists have, however, made the economy their special area of study, one important aspect of which is the allocation of scarce resources.
Many economists regard the methods of economics as applicable to a wide range of social issues, but that is not the same as thinking that all social problems are economics problems, or that the economy is something other than one aspect of society. Similarly, other disciplines, such as sociology and politics, also study the economy in revealing and helpful ways, as one aspect of society. But, as in those other disciplines, economists do not have a single view; in particular, not all equate economics with a view that markets are the best way to allocate resources in all cases. Horton implies that all economics involves the promotion of market mechanisms, which is another false conflation.
Political economy and morality: “Once there was political economy=economics, ethics, politics. Economists have stripped morality from economics, leaving an arid science.”[4] Horton echoes common misconceptions among lay observers of social science issues about the origins and meaning of the term political economy. Originally, it meant more or less exactly what we now call economics, not the mixture with ethics and politics that he suggests. Now, it no longer has a single meaning, and is therefore less useful than it might be. The suggestion that economics as practised excludes morals has no foundation. Economics is no different to, say, physics, chemistry, and biology, which as sciences have, for example, all developed weapons of mass destruction of many and various kinds. Viewed in that narrow way, all sciences are arid, including medical science. But none of them exclude or replace moral and ethical issues in the way that their findings are put in practice.
Theories or data? “The high points of economic thinking are theories, not data. Reliable experimentally derived data are anathema for most economists.”[5] Thinking without data can be useful—as with philosophy—and theories are helpful in interpretation of data. Throughout much of the time during which economics has developed, very few economic data were available, they were hard to collect, and there was no scope for experimentation. But modern economics no longer has such constraints, and the consequence is that empirical analysis dominates. Indeed, the most ambitious and expensive randomised controlled trials ever conducted were designed and analysed by economists: the Rand Health Insurance Experiment,[13] and the Negative Income Tax Experiments.[14]
Health, goods, costs, and value: “Economists see health as an economic good. It is an opportunity cost, with zero intrinsic value.”[6] The claim that economists see health as an economic good is probably true for most economists; economic goods are defined as goods or services that are scarce relative to society's desire for them. Health is a very unusual good, because it is intangible (although sickness is not), and cannot be traded, because it is intrinsic to people and cannot be transferred.
What Horton might really have meant is health care, which does not have those unusual characteristics. It is not an invention of economists; unless physicians have had independent incomes, they have always had to make their living by selling their services. The concept of opportunity cost, however, is an invention of economists. It is not a characteristic of goods themselves, and reframes the cost of production in terms of the value of the benefits forgone in the use of resources to produce the next-best good. This notion brings out the economic reality of resource scarcity: to consume something means to give up something else. Nothing is, in this sense, free (not even free lunches, which consume time that could have been spent doing something else). Economists would be stupid indeed to believe that health and health care have no intrinsic value, because if they had no value, why would people be willing to incur opportunity costs to obtain them? In fact, health economists have been at the forefront of the definition and measurement of the value of health care, to ensure that decisions about health care are not made solely on the basis of costs. The UK's National Institute for Health and Care Excellence (NICE) does not take quality-adjusted life-years, and other measures of the benefits of health care, into account just because doctors say that it should.
Rationality and cost—benefit analysis: “Rationality, for the economist, means subjecting every thought/decision to a cost-benefit analysis. A wholly narrow view of humanity.”[7] Rationality in economics simply means that people behave in ways consistent with their preferences. It is not the only definition of rationality, of course, and should be regarded as a technical term, not an assertion about what rationality in a more general sense means. Rationality is certainly not meant to be prescriptive, or to describe a mental state. It is a simplifying assumption in the analysis of human behaviour, not a description of how people actually behave. If this assumption works—that's fine. If not, more sophisticated assumptions are needed, and economics has traditionally explored many different assumptions about how people make decisions. For example, in his Theory of Moral Sentiments,[15] Adam Smith said: “How selfish soever man may be supposed, there are evidently some principles in his nature, which interest him in the fortune of others, and render their happiness necessary to him, though he derives nothing from it except the pleasure of seeing it.” Behavioural economics is almost entirely devoted to the study of non-rational behaviour, and most economists would agree with the view that cost—benefit decisions are applicable only to a narrow range of aspects of humanity. An important distinction is between individual decision making and decisions taken by public bodies such as NICE. Because NICE affects the use and allocation of public money, most people (not just economists) want a transparent decision process that involves the consideration of costs and benefits. Tossing a coin might be fine (and rational) for individuals' decisions involving their own resources, but not for NICE and taxpayers' money.
Markets: “The big idea in economics is the market. The assumption is that human beings make cost-benefit decisions based only on self-interest. No.”[8] The most serious error here is the implication that markets are in some way an idea invented by economists. As implied above, markets are real phenomena that predate economics by many years. Markets are networks of buyers and sellers, whose transactions can be governed by differing motives. Economists have made a study of them, and because markets have historically been an important part of economies, economics involves a lot of market analysis.
Analysis of markets does not require that people make cost—benefit decisions based only on self-interest. True, there is often a simplifying assumption that suppliers to markets aim to maximise profits (the difference between costs and income), but it is not the only possibility. In health economics this assumption is rarely used, because it is rarely relevant, certainly for health-care institutions. It is even sometimes not true for individual physicians. Those who purchase in a market are usually assumed to have some self-interest, but the most common analyses use the household rather than individuals, which implies some collective interests (albeit narrow relative to society as a whole). But, as the earlier quote from Adam Smith suggests, people do take others' interests into account, even those of unknown strangers, and that is particularly important for the analysis of health care. Even introductory economics textbooks include a discussion of external costs and benefits.
Prices and souls: “The essence of economics is price. For those in health who argue for access free at point of delivery, we kill the soul of the economist.”[9] Economists have indeed made a special study of the role of price in resource allocation. Prices are a financial incentive that affect how people behave in the supply or consumption of goods and services. However, economists also recognise that the use of a price mechanism is just one way to ration goods. There are many other ways, such as distribution according to needs, waiting times, or on a first-come-first-served basis. If a society—as in the UK—decides that another way of rationing better satisfies its aims (such as equal access to health care for equal need), there is no economic theory that suggests it is wrong. Such a decision has consequences, of course, not least the necessity to decide the criteria to determine which people should have access to what resources. Alternative methods to allocate resources should be subjected to the same analysis and evaluation as price mechanisms. However, economists also recognise the distributional consequences of resource allocation by the use of prices, which is why there is so much support among them for non-price mechanisms in health care. If economists have souls, they have the same essence as other people's.
Citizens and consumers: “Economists deny the existence of citizens. They see only consumers.”[10] When economists analyse consumption, people are often modelled as consumers. But when production is analysed, people are seen as producers; in selling they are sellers; and so on. Moreover, economists also analyse different collective levels at which economic actions and decisions take place, such as individuals, households, firms, and governments. There is no presumption that the individual as consumer is the preferred decision unit. More importantly, those who emphasise economic roles as the key relationship that people have with society regard that as a definition of citizenship, not a replacement for it. To be an economist does not mean to subscribe to this concept of citizenship, though many who are not economists do so. Nothing in economics denies the existence of citizens.
Worsening lives and inequality: “Finally, it's acceptable to worsen the lives of some provided the gains of others compensate. Economists institutionalise inequality.”[11] Mainstream economics in fact has a lot of problems with trade-offs between one person's gain and another's loss, to an extent which often renders economic analysis powerless and of theoretical interest only. Key theoretical ideas include the Pareto criterion, which suggests that we cannot say one state of the world is better than another unless at least one person gains and no-one loses, and the impossibility of making interpersonal comparisons of utility. Welfare economics and social choice theory struggle to create a coherent framework for the analysis of such issues. If anything, this analysis has a disabling effect on economists' ability to judge such dilemmas, and does not give them the simple short-cut to say that such trade-offs are always acceptable. Physicians, and others engaged in decision making in the real world, have few such inhibitions, and cannot afford them because otherwise their decision making would be paralysed.
However, economists have led initiatives to help with such difficult decisions. Economic evaluations make clear the costs and benefits of different options, and should also quantify the distributional effects of decisions or actions. The latter is admittedly less often undertaken because of the difficulties involved. Economists have undertaken many empirical analyses of inequality in both wealth and health,[16, 17] and made proposals to mitigate gross inequalities in economies. Far from institutionalising inequalities, economists have exposed the problems decision makers face, devised ways to measure the problem, and suggested ways to deal with it.
What motivated Horton's critical outburst about economics and economists is not clear. More than 40 years ago, an essay by Alan Williams to defend economic evaluation admitted its imperfections, but concluded with Maurice Chevalier's view on old age: “Well, there is quite a lot I don't like about it, but it's not so bad when you consider the alternative!”[18] Economics, like medicine, is imperfect. The challenge for practitioners of each is to ensure that the perfect does not drive out the good. Our practices may at times be imperfect, but that should not inhibit our drive to improve clinical practice and economic activity for the benefit of all our patients and citizens. We all must strive to avoid confused analysis in displays of modest understanding of each other's work.

Seven Deadly Innocent Frauds of Economic Policy

Seven Deadly Innocent Frauds of Economic Policy   


Warren Mosler Talks Economics
https://www.youtube.com/watch?v=q7_7oC2xfYE
Warren Mosler's Soft Currency Economics
https://www.youtube.com/watch?v=Z1uWVj0YJ3M

The 7 Deadly Innocent Frauds of Economic Policy 
 - Introduction
http://goo.gl/PDOQ8d
- Full Text (pdf File)
Seven Deadly Innocent Frauds of Economic Policy   
http://goo.gl/kht79
Mosler's "Seven Deadly Innocent Frauds"--a review, sort of
http://www.dailykos.com/stories/2011/12/16/1045963/-

Why Free-market Economics Is a Fraud     
http://www.huffingtonpost.com/ian-fletcher/free-market-economics-critique_b_1155820.html

Friday, April 15, 2016

Sorrowful & Moody Music from South America - Pan Flute (Collection)

Sorrowful & Moody Music from South America - Pan Flute (Collection)

​ 
Leo Rojas - Der letzte Mohikaner - YouTube
https://www.youtube.com/watch?v=vupbjmYhpgQ&list=PLGEDwqYmb0hKXLsHOPlL82tS3Oa_OGGa7&index=15

Thursday, April 14, 2016

A word with the most multiple meanings

A word with the most multiple meanings 

10 English Words with the most multiple meanings 
– Part 1
- Part 2
Multiple Meaning Words
WORDS WITH MORE THAN ONE MEANING 
List of words having different meanings in American and British English: A–L
M–Z

What Is Linguistics?

What Is Linguistics?
A Brief Introduction to the Many Branches of Linguistics
utterance (speech)
Language Purism
Parsing - a traditional grammatical exercise 
Winston Churchill's Grammar Lessons: Parsing Past and Present
http://goo.gl/005Yqb
Texting
http://grammar.about.com/od/tz/g/textingterm.htm

"Oxymoron"

"Oxymoron" - an essential ingredient in a thump-jumping speech!
Oxymoron
http://grammar.about.com/od/mo/g/oxymoronterm.htm
Examples of Oxymorons
Oxymoron Examples | Oxymoron Definition | Examples of Oxymorons (Oxymora)
100 Awfully Good Examples of Oxymorons
 "Semantic procedure" is an oxymoron
https://goo.gl/m2A7Tw
A Linguistic Study of Oxymoron
http://www.iasj.net/iasj?func=fulltext&aId=46502

Etymology - the study of the history of words, their origins, and how their form and meaning have changed over time

Wednesday, April 13, 2016

Documentary : Nostradamus

Documentary : Nostradamus

The Man Who Saw Tomorrow
Documentary Nostradamus The Truth 
​- ​
Discovery Channel
Nostradamus - The man who saw tomorrow - Orson Welles
ABC Nostradamus - The Man Who Saw Tomorrow - Part 1-3 

The Next Nostradamus. Documentary , History
Documentary Nostradamus
​-​
 The Truth Discovery Channel Special History Documentary 

Nostradamus (1994)
The Other Nostradamus
Prophecies Of Nostradamus (1979) complete

Nostradamus 2012 End Time
Nostradamus : What Will Happen When The Dollar Collapse In 2016
5 Nostradamus Predictions and Visions for 2016 .( world w-a-r.I.I.I.)

Tuesday, April 12, 2016

An incredibly magnificient piece of Fado!

Your Love - ENNIO MORRICONE & DULCE PONTES 
 - Relaxing & Romantic Music
https://www.youtube.com/watch?v=elwWEauggzM&index=18&list=RDAcL7UemRuWU&nohtml5=False

A Film/Theme : Queimada!/Burn!(1969):Marlon Brando e Gillo Pontecorvo/LEGENDADO

A Film/Theme : Queimada!/Burn!(1969):Marlon Brando e Gillo Pontecorvo/LEGENDADO

Film 
https://www.youtube.com/watch?v=tQBHr8pjGXI&nohtml5=False

Theme Music
Ennio Morricone - Queimada - 01.Abolição
https://goo.gl/R3k6Jj

Collection (Philharmonic)
Ennio Morricone - Abolisson (In Concerto - Venezia 10.11.07)
https://goo.gl/5jlIqK
Ennio Morricone, Abolison, Arena Concerto Live (Another Style) 

Ennio/Bocelli & Fado

Andrea Bocelli and Dulce Pontes - O Mare E Tu
https://goo.gl/fynVH7
Dulce Pontes _ & E. Morricone _ Ballad of Sacco & Vanzetti _
https://goo.gl/AQqg6a
Dulce Pontes & E. Morricone _ La Luz Prodigiosa _ Mina + Dulce Pontes + Amalia 
https://goo.gl/MefRHl









Monday, April 11, 2016

Ennio Morricone - BBC Documentary (1995) - Part 1 & 2 - YouTube

Ennio Morricone - BBC Documentary (1995) - Part 1 & 2 - YouTube


Ennio Morricone - BBC Documentary (1995) - Part 1
https://www.youtube.com/watch?v=R9uMeQoDf5Y&index=3&list=RDTj6MWE4wZx4

Ennio Morricone -- BBC2 Documentary

BBC The Richest Songs in the World
https://www.youtube.com/watch?v=supZlAbSARc&nohtml5=False

The Joy of the Single (45 / 7") - BBC
https://goo.gl/Fc4cdB

The Village Soundtrack- The Gravel Road
https://www.youtube.com/watch?v=1ro4FHd51t4&index=4&list=RDYKjwHY_5nfk&nohtml5=False
THE VILLAGE Complete Score
https://goo.gl/J6aI4O

Sunday, April 10, 2016

大大咧咧的活著 - 句句穿透心肺

大大咧咧的活著。

《什么叫活着 ! (句句穿透心肺。》

人生說到底,還是要靠自己。
生病了,自己去買藥;
天冷了,記得加衣服;
感覺餓了,就去找吃的。

一切過不去的心情,睡一覺就好;
所有放不下的感情,給自己開導。

被人在乎,就掏出心來珍惜;
有人討厭,就離他遠一點。
忍耐久了,就發一次脾氣;
壓抑多了,就大哭一場。

看別人的眼色,
不如做自己的本色;
小心翼翼的撐著,
不如大大咧咧的活著。
人就這一輩子,別太對不起自己!

不是所有的疲憊,
都要說出來;
不是所有的眼淚,
都要流出來。

汗水打濕了鬢角,才知生活的苦與累;
淚水吞進了肚裡,才懂沒人能真幫你。

你不屈,你不服,你從不認輸,
心裡的苦也從不說出;
你堅持,你堅韌,你一直堅守,
暗藏的泪流在无人处。

你很想歇一歇,但總有幹不完的事情;
你渴望停一停,但還有離不開的家庭。
肩上的壓力,
是生存的難題;
心中的壓抑,
又是不能說的委屈。
當淚水流下的一刻,
你有資格好好發洩;
當身體疲憊的時分,
你更有權力好好休息。

風雨以後,彩虹是倔強的美麗;
脆弱過後,堅強是選擇的唯一。

做人不易,但永不說放棄;
生活不易,更需要堅持的勇氣!

天一身心靈研討中心共勉